European Vaccine-rollout Policy, Unraveled Markets, and Moral Externalities
DOI:
https://doi.org/10.5755/j01.eis.1.17.32091Keywords:
moral negative externality, moral transaction costs, risk aversion, European integration, unraveled markets, Covid-19 vaccination rolout policyAbstract
This paper seeks to address the role of European public policy in addressing the problem of Covid-19 vaccine-rollout policy. Currently in Europe, instead of market-based allocation a centralized command-based approach has been implemented to address the essential questions of production and distribution of vaccines throughout the EU. This is centralized, command-based decision-making on the allocation of vaccines which is leading to political and sociological tensions among EU Member States. Paper argues that in order to mitigate these shortcomings European public policy could employ a more nuanced approach. While employing law and economics tools this paper addresses the questions on how European societies should allocate vaccine and, more importantly, who should make this allocation decisions. Moreover, identified moral negative externalities, status quo and omission biases, planning fallacy, risk aversion, administrative rigidity, notorious type-I-type-II error fallacy and related unraveled markets phenomena might result in vaccine-rollout failures.
References
-Abbot A. Thomas, and John A. Vernon, “The Cost of US Pharmaceutical Price Reductions: A Financial Simulation Model of R&D Decisions,” Managerial and Decision Economics 28(4-5), 2007, 293-306.
-Akerloff A. George, “The Market for Lemons: Quality, Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism,” 84 Quarterly Journal of Economics 488, 1970.
-Arrow J Kenneth, “Gifts and exchanges,” 1 Phil. & Pub. Affairs, 343, 1972.
-Ashlagi Itai, Marko Braverman, and Avinatan Hassidim, “Stability in Large Matching Markets with Complementarities,” Operations Research 62, no. 4, 2014, 713-732.
-Bhaskarabhatla, A.S., Anurag, P., Chatterjee, C & Pennings, H.P.G. (2016). Mitigating Regulatory Impact: The Case of Partial Price Controls on Metformin in India. Health Policy and Planning.
-Van den Bergh Roger, “Farewell Utopia? Why the European Union should take the Economics of Federalism Seriously.” 23 Maastricht Journal of International and European Law 6, 2016.
-Van den Bergh, “The roundabouts of European law and economics,” Eleven International Publishing, 2018, at pp. 21-28.
-Blumenthal A. Jeremy, “Group Deliberation and the Endowment Effect: An Experimental Study,” 50 Hous. L. Rev. 41, 2012.
-Buehler Roger, Dale Griffin and Michael Ross, „ Exploring the planning fallacy: why people underestimate their task completion times,” 67 J. Personality & Soc. Psychology 366, 1994.
-Buehler Roger, Dale Griffin and Johanna Peetz, “The Planning Fallacy: Cognitive, Motivational and Social Origins,” 42 Advances Experimental Social Psychology 1, 2010.
-Cheung, Steven NS. "Theory of Price Control, A." JL & Econ. 17 (1974): 53.
- Coase H. Ronald, “The Nature of the Firm,” 4 Economica 386, 1937.
-Coase H. Ronald, “The Federal Communications Commission,” 2 Journal of Law and Economics, 1959, 1-40.
-Coase H. Ronald, “The problem of social cost,” 3 Journal of law and economics, 1960, 1-44.
-Cohen R. Lloyd, “Holdouts and free riders,” 20 Journal of Legal Studies, 1991, pp. 357-376.
-Cooter Robert and Thomas Ulen, “Law and Economics,” 6th ed., Pearson, 2016, pp 40-42.
-Danzon, P M, “Making Sense of Drug Prices,” Regulation, volume 23, issue 1, 2000.
-Dawes, M. Robyn, David Faust and Paul E. Meehl, “Clinical versus Actuarial Judgement,” 243 SCI. 1668, 1989.
-De Geest, Gerrit, “Contract Law and Economics – Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Volume 6,” 2nd ed., Edward Elgar Cheltenham, 2011.
-Demsetz Harold, “Toward a theory of property rights,” 57 American Economic Review Papers & proceedings 347, 1967, pp. 351-353.
-Dimasi, J A, R W Hansen, H G Grabowski, “The price of innovation: new estimates of drug development costs,” J Health Economics, volume 22, p. 151 – 185, 2003.
-Dixit A and Nalebuff B (1991) Thinking Strategically: The Competitive Edge in Business, Politics and Everyday Life. New York: Norton.
-Downs, A., “Inside Bureaucracy 81,” Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1967.
-Eggertsson Thrainn, “Economic behaviour and institutions,” Cambridge University Press, 1990.
-Elster Jon, “Explaining social behaviour: more nuts and bolts for the social sciences,” Cambridge University Press, 2007.
-Fong T. Geoffrey, David H. Krantz and Richard Nisbett, “The Effects of Statistical Training on Thinking about Everyday Life, 18 Cognitive Psychol. 253, 1986.
-Fudenberg Drew and Jean Tirole, “Game theory,” MIT Press, 1996.
-George F. Joey, Kevin Duffy and Manju Ahuja, “Countering the Anchoring Bias with Decision Support Systems, 29 Decision Support Systems 195, 2000.
-Gordon H. Scott, “The Economic theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery,” 62 Journal of Political Economy 2, 1954.
-Hardin G., “The Tragedy of the Commons,” 162 Science 3859, 1968, pp. 1243-1248.
-Hong Fuhai, Tanjim Hossain and John A. List, “Framing Manipulations in Contests: A Natural Field Experiment, 118 J. Econ. Behav. & Org. 372, 2015.
-Hirshleifer Jack, “Price theory and applications,” 3rd ed., Cambridge University Press, 1984.
-Hirt R. Edward and Keith D. Markman, “Multiple Explanation: A Consider-an-Alternative Strategy for Debiasing Judgements,” 69 J. Personality and Soc. Psychol. 1069, 1995.
-Jackson H-E, Kaplow L, Shavell S-M, Viscusi W-K and Cope D (2003) Analytical Methods for Lawyers. New York: Foundation Press.
-Kahn E. Barbara, Mary Frances Luce, and Stephen M. Nowlis, “Debiasing Insights from Process Tests,” 33 J. Consumer res. 131, 2006.
-Kahneman Daniel and Amos Tversky, “Intuitive Prediction: Biases and Corrective Procedures,” in Daniel Kahneman, Paul Slovic and Amos Tversky (eds.), Judgement Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, 1988.
-Kahneman Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard H. Thaler, “The endowment effect, loss aversion and status quo bias,” 5 Journal of economic perspectives 193, 197-99, 1991.
-Kameda Tatsuya and James H. David, “The Function of Reference Point in Individual and Group Risk Decision Making,” 46 Org. Behav. & Hum. Decision Processes 55, 1990.
-Katz, Michael and Sherwin Rosen, “Microeconomics,” 3rd ed., McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 1997.
-Kessler, Daniel P. "The effects of pharmaceutical price controls on the cost and quality of medical care: a review of the empirical literature." draft paper submitted to the US International Trade Administration (2004): 3.
-Kobayashi H. Bruce and Ribstein E. Larry, “Economics of Federalism,” Edward Elgar, 2007.
-Kreps David, “A course in microeconomic theory,” Princeton University Press, 1990.
-Krugman, Paul, “Vaccines: A Very European Disaster When policymakers are averse to the wrong risks,” The New York Times, March 18, 2021.
-Larrick, P. Richard, James N. Morgan and Richard E. Nisbett, “Teaching the Use of Cost-Benefit Reasoning in Everyday Life,” 1 Psychol. Sci. 362, 1990.
-Larick P. Richard, “Debiasing,” in Derek Koehler and Nigel Harvey (eds.), 1 Blackwell Handbook of Judgement and Decision Making, Wiley Blackwell, 2004.
-Laughlin R. Patrick, and Alan L. Ellis, “Demonstrability and Social Combination Processes on Mathematical Intellective Taks, 22 J. Experimental Soc. Psychol. 177, 1986.
-Leitzel Jim, “Concepts in Law and Economics,” Oxford University Press, 2015, p. 108.
-Lerner, S. Jennifer, and Philip E. Tetlock, “Accounting for the Effects of Accountability,” 125 Psychol. Bull. 255, 1999.
-Lerner, S. Jennifer and Philip E. Tetlock, “Bridging Individual, Interpersonal, and Institutional Approaches to Judgement and Choice: The Impact of Accountability on Cognitive Bias,” in Sandra L. Schneider and James Shanteau (eds.), “Emerging Perspectives on Judgement and Decision Research, Cambridge University Press, 2003, 431-457.
-Lord G. Charles, Mark R. Lepper, and Elizabeth Preston, “Considering the Opposite: A Corrective Strategy for Social Judgement,” 47 J. Personality & Soc. Psychology 1231, 1984.
-Luce R. Duncan and Raiffa Howard, “Games and decisions,” Wiley, 1957.
-MacKaay Ejan, “Law and Economics for Civil Law Systems,” Edward Elgar, 2015, pp. 205-207.
-Magen Stefan, “Game theory and collective goods,” in Towfigh V. Emanuel and Niels Petersen (eds.), “Economic methods for lawyers,” Edward Elgar, 2015, pp.78-80.
-Marwell, G., & Oliver, P. (1993). The critical mass in collective action. Cambridge University Press.
-Miller L. Roger, Daniel K. Benjamin and Douglas C. North, “The economics of public policy issues,” 20th ed., Pearson, 2017.
-Musgrave A. Richard, The Theory of Public Finance: A Study in Public Economy, 1959.
-Mussweiler Thomas, Fritz Strack and Tim Pfeiffer, “Overcoming the Inevitable Achoring-Effect: Considering the Opposite Compensates for Selective Accesibility,” 26 Personality & Soc. Psychol. Bull. 1142, 2000.
-Nisbett E. Richard, Rules for Reasoning. Psychology Press, 1993.
-Niskanen, W. A., Bureaucracy and representative government, Chicago: Aldine, 1971.
-Oates, Wallace E., “Fiscal Federalism,” London, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1972.
-Ogus Anthony, “Regulation: Legal Form and Economic Theory,” Hart Publishing 2004, at p.99.
-Olson M (1965). The Logic of Collective Action. Boston, Harvard University Press.
-Paese W. Paul, Mary Bieser, and Mark E. Tubbs, “Framing Effects and Choice Shifts in Group Decision Making,” 56 Org. Behav. & Hum. Decision Processes 149, 1993.
-Pigou C. Arthur, “The economics of welfare,” London, Macmillan, 1932.
-Posner A. Richard, “Economic Analysis of Law,” 8th ed., Wolters Kluwer Law Publishers, 2011.
-Radin, Jane Margaret, “Contested Commodities,” 1996.
-Rose-Ackerman, Susan, “Reforming Public Bureaucracy through Economic Incentives?,” 2 Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 1, 1986, 131-161.
-Roth, E. Alvin, “The Economist as Engineer: Game Theory, Experimentation, and Computation as Tools for Design Economics,” 70 Econometrica 4, 2002, 1341–1378.
-Roth, E. Alvin, “Repugnance as a Constraint on Markets,” 21 Journal of Economic Perspectives 3, 2007.
-Roth, E Alvin, “Matching with Couples: Stability and Incentives in Large Markets,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 4, 128, 2013, 1585-1632
-Samuelson William and Richard Zeckhouser, “Status quo bias and decision making,” 1 Journal of risk and uncertainty 7, 1988.
-Schelling T (1960) The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
-Schweitzer Maurice, “Disentangling status quo and omission effects: an experimental analysis, 58 Organizational behaviour and human decision processes 457, 1994.
-Siegel.Jacobs Karen and Frank J. Yates, „Effects of Procedural Accountability on Judgement Quality,” 65 Org. Behav. & Human Decision Processes 1, 1996.
-Soll B. Jack, Katherine L. Milkman & John W. Payne, “A User’s Guide to Debiasing,” in Gideon Keren and George Wu (eds.), 2 Wiley Blackwell Handbook of Judgement and Decision Making, Wiley Blackwell, 2015).
-Stallard Jo Merrie and Debra L. Worthington, “Reducing the Hindsight Bias Utilizing Attorney Closing Arguments,” 22 Law & Hum. Behav. 671, 1998.
-Taylor Michael, “The possibility of co-operation,” Cambridge University Press, 1987.
-Tetlock E. Philip and Richard Boettger, “Accountability Amplifies the Status Quo Effect when Change Creates Victims,” 7 J. Behav. Decision Making 1, 1994.
-Thaler Richard, “Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice,” 1 Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation 39, 1980.
-Tobin James, “On limiting the Domain of Inequality, 13 Journal of Law and Economics 263, 1970.
-Towfigh, V. Emanuel, and Niels Petersen, “Public and social choice theory,” in Towfigh, V Emanuel and Niels Petersen (eds.), Economic methods for lawyers,” Edward Elgar, 121-146, 2015.
-Tullock, G., “The Politics of Bureaucracy,” Public affairs press, 1965.
-Tversky Amos and Daniel Kahneman, “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk,” 47 Econometrica 263, 1979.
-Viscusi, W. K., “Fatal trade-offs: public and private responsibilities for risk,” Oxford University Press, 1992.
-Viscusi, W. K., “Regulation of health, safety and environmental risks,” in Polinsky, A. Mitchell and Steven Shavell (eds.), “Handbook of law and economics,” Vol. 1., North-Holland, 2007.
-Wittman Donald, “Economic Foundation of Law and Organization,” Cambridge University Press, 2006, at p. 350.
-Willer, R. (2009). Groups reward individual sacrifice: The status solution to the collective action problem. American Sociological Review, 74(1), 23-43.
-Zamir Eyal and Doron Teichman, “Behavioral Law and Economics,” Oxford University Press, 2020.
Downloads
Published
Issue
Section
License
This article is an Open Access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 (CC BY 4.0) License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).